AI Drives Economic Growth by Boosting Productivity, Lowering Prices, and Enhancing Wages

Imagine the United States at the beginning of the 20th century. Streets were still dominated by horse-drawn carriages, while early automobiles were dismissed as noisy novelties for the wealthy. Within decades, the internal combustion engine transformed society—sparking new industries such as road construction, suburban development, logistics, and mass tourism. While some traditional jobs disappeared, like those of buggy-whip makers, far more opportunities emerged in entirely new sectors. The broader economic gains in productivity, wages, and living standards far outweighed the losses.

This historical shift offers a valuable lens through which to view today’s advancements in artificial intelligence (AI). A recent report from the U.S. Senate HELP Committee claims that worker pay has not kept pace with productivity and warns AI could displace up to 97 million jobs. However, this analysis overlooks the dynamic nature of economic evolution. Much like early critics who counted displaced blacksmiths but ignored the rise of auto mechanics and highway engineers, the report focuses narrowly on potential job displacement while missing the larger picture of innovation-driven growth.

In reality, productivity and compensation are closely linked. Using comprehensive data from the Bureau of Labor Statistics and FRED, real hourly compensation for nonfarm workers rose from 67.46 in 1973Q1 to 109.21 in 2025Q2 (2017=100), an increase of approximately 61.9%. This demonstrates that as productivity improves, so does worker pay—especially when supported by technological progress.

The projection of 97 million jobs being replaced relies on a flawed methodology that equates task automation with job elimination, without accounting for new roles created, shifts in consumer demand, or the emergence of complementary industries. Economies do not simply shed jobs; they reallocate labor. Just as cars reshaped transportation work, AI will transform knowledge-based tasks—automating routine processes, amplifying high-value work, and generating new career paths.

Historical patterns with transformative technologies—such as steam, electricity, and computing—show consistent outcomes: productivity climbs, unit costs fall, employment structures evolve, and overall compensation increases. Early studies on AI adoption reveal double-digit productivity gains in customer service and professional writing, with the most significant improvements seen among less-experienced staff. This mirrors past transitions where entry-level workers gained access to new ladders of opportunity.

Moreover, industrial automation research shows that increased robot usage contributed about 0.36 percentage points annually to labor productivity growth, improved total factor productivity, reduced output prices, and did not lead to net job losses.

Consumers also benefit significantly. AI reduces the cost of cognitive tasks—such as drafting, coding, and information retrieval—allowing businesses to serve more customers efficiently. In competitive markets, these efficiencies translate into lower prices and better services, enhancing overall welfare.

To maximize these benefits, policy should focus on accelerating AI adoption across small businesses, education, and public institutions—similar to past efforts like rural electrification. Ensuring market competition is vital so that cost savings reach both workers and consumers. Where skills are in demand and productivity rises, wages can increase; where competition is strong, prices can fall.

The evidence is clear: AI functions more as an economic engine than a job destroyer. It enhances output, reduces costs, and, when paired with supportive policies, lifts incomes across the workforce. Rather than resisting change, the goal should be to manage transitions effectively—ensuring all Americans can participate in and benefit from this technological shift.
— news from CCIA

— News Original —
AI Is an Economic Engine Propelling Productivity and Wages Up, and Prices Down
Picture America in 1905. Horse-drawn carriages still clip-clop down Main Street. A few noisy contraptions sputter by, derided as rich men’s toys. Within a generation, the internal combustion engine rewires the economy by adding millions of new professions that never existed during the buggy era: the need for assembly lines and paved roads, construction of suburbs, motels, logistics networks, mass tourism, faster ambulances, and fresher food. n nDo we mourn the lost buggy-whip manufacturers? Or do we celebrate the far larger gains in productivity, pay, and consumer well-being that the car era unlocked? n nThe latter is the right framing for today’s debate over artificial intelligence (AI), necessitating a more holistic look at how the job market will look in an AI-integrated economy. For example, a recent U.S. Senate Health, Education, Labor & Pensions (HELP) Committee minority staff report inaccurately claims that real wages do not rise with productivity and warns that AI could “replace” nearly 100 million jobs. Unfortunately, the HELP committee report does not appreciate the bigger economic picture—just like the early car critics who tallied lost blacksmiths without counting the auto mechanic, the road builder, the freight dispatcher, the motel owner, and the family that could now afford fresh produce year-round. The HELP report focuses on the buggy whip; sound economics focuses on the engine. n nProductivity drives compensation higher n nThe HELP report’s marquee claim that productivity does not drive worker compensation higher relies on a flawed measure. Economists generally use real hourly compensation (wages plus benefits per hour) as the apples-to-apples counterpart to productivity. On that more comprehensive measure, workers’ purchasing power is well above 1973 and correlates strongly with productivity. For example, the BLS/FRED series “Real Hourly Compensation for All Workers, Nonfarm Business” (2017=100) rises from 67.46 in 1973Q1 to 109.21 in 2025Q2, an increase of about 61.9%. In other words, productivity increases have pushed labor compensation higher, and will continue to do so. Workers benefit from productivity-enhancing innovations, as they boost worker compensation. n n“97 million jobs replaced” is a horse-and-buggy projection assuming no auto industry n nThe headline job-loss number in the HELP report relies on a methodology which scores tasks to produce an occupation-level “automation score,” which it interprets as job displacement amounting to around 97 million. That approach equates task exposure with job loss, assumes near-frictionless adoption within a decade, and omits standard general-equilibrium channels, including but not limited to price declines, demand expansion, task creation, and worker flows. Quite literally, the methodology assumes jobs can only go away and never be created. n nThat is not how the economy works, and it is not how technology diffuses. The car didn’t just “replace” carriage drivers; it reorganized work. We re-bundled tasks, built entirely new industries, and expanded markets because travel got cheaper and faster. AI will do the same for knowledge work: routine tasks get automated, high-value tasks scale, and entirely new complements emerge. That’s the engine effect. n nWhat history and early evidence actually show n nWhen general-purpose technologies develop like steam, electricity, the motor, or software, four things happen: n nProductivity rises. The increased productivity is the motivation for adopting the new technology. n nUnit costs fall and prices follow in competitive markets. Cheaper transport made goods and services more affordable for consumers; AI will do the same for digital and service workflows. n nEmployment composition shifts as some tasks shrink and new ones scale. Aggregate employment doesn’t collapse; it reallocates. n nOverall compensation rises as a result of competitive reallocations in a higher-productivity economy. n nThe best early AI field studies already show double-digit productivity gains in customer support and professional writing, with the biggest boosts for less-experienced workers—exactly the human-capital story you want if you care about inclusive growth. That pattern mirrors the automobile era, where entry-level mechanics and service workers rode a new ladder of opportunity even as blacksmithing waned. It also echoes the introduction of modern industrial robots, where increased robot use “contributed approximately 0.36 percentage points to annual labor productivity growth” while raising total factor productivity, lowering output prices, and not significantly reducing total employment. n nConsumers are the big winners n nCars didn’t just create jobs; they slashed the effective price of distance. AI slashes the effective price of cognition—drafting, summarizing, coding, searching, troubleshooting. When the “cognitive miles per gallon” goes up, firms can serve more customers per worker-hour. In competitive markets, those savings show up as lower prices and better service. That’s not just a theory; it’s how every new general purpose technology has worked. n nSo what should policy do: protect buggy whips or scale engines? n nA pro-worker, pro-competition agenda embraces the engine and manages the transition: n nAccelerate diffusion. Help small firms, schools, and public agencies adopt modern AI copilots and workflows. As with rural electrification and the interstate system, the broad gains come when everyone can plug into the new technology. n nKeep markets contestable. Competition policy based on application of the consumer welfare standard should ensure cost savings flow through to workers and consumers: higher pay where skills are scarce and productivity rises, lower prices where firms compete and new efficiencies reduce costs. We see intense competition between firms making large investments in innovation, infrastructure, and service improvements in the AI space today, strongly suggesting a healthy ecosystem for consumer welfare enhancement. n nThe economic bottom line n nAmerica isn’t enriched by freezing the economy in the horse-and-buggy era. Our economic successes are driven by building around innovative technologies—creating new tasks, new revenue streams, and new ways to live. The same logic applies now. When we look at technology honestly, AI is much more of an economic engine than a buggy whip guillotine: it raises productivity, pushes down prices, and, with the right complements, lifts pay for many workers. n nWe honor the past by helping people through the transition, not by trying to stop the engine. The buggy whip had its moment. The AI opportunity now—like the automobile then—is to make sure every American can take the wheel.

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *